Posts Tagged ‘Philippine policy making’


Concluding remarks

 

If one is to assess the efficacy of the banking liberalization using the economic efficiency standards of liberalized markets, then it was a failure.  It did not bring down the cost of money, did not narrow intermediation spreads (the gap between bank borrowing, i.e., deposit rates, and lending rates), and did not increase the supply of loanable funds to the cash-strapped economic groups and sectors, including agri-business and venture capitalists/entrepreneurs.  Under the relatively-constricted terms of financial liberalization, the new banks came in only to cater to the already competitive but still lucrative high-end corporate market.

This lack of potency can only be explained satisfactorily by the mangling of the terms and the intent of the banking liberalization law.  To the extent that the law hewed closely to the preferences of the financial oligopolists, then it signifies another notch up their sleeves.  To the extent, however, that new players have come in and may be able to offer significant competition in the future, then the law can be considered a skillful compromise as well as an opportunity for thorough-going financial openness.  The future course of events is, of course, an empirical matter that could not be settled in this paper.  One can only speculate and perhaps hope for a more competitive financial regime that can offer cheaper credit to all fund users but still able to afford investors with respectable yields and acceptable risks.

REFERENCES

  1. Books and Journal Articles

“Liberalization and the Transformation of the Philippine Economy.” Governor’s Page, CB Review 44(4): 1-2.

Alesina, Alberto and Guido Tabellini. 1989. “External Debt, Capital Flight, and Political Risk.” Journal of Development Economics 27(2): 199-221.

Andrews, David. 1994. “Capital Mobility and State Autonomy: Towards a Structural Theory of International Monetary Relations.” International Studies Quarterly 38(2): 193-218.

De Dios, Emmanuel. 1996. “Resource Mobilization and Industrial Organization.” In Financial Sector Issues in the Philippines, pp. 55-82. Edited by Raul Fabella and Kazuhisa Ito. Tokyo: Institute for Developing Economies.

Frieden, Jeffrey. 1991. “”Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45(4): 425-51.

_____________and Ronald Rogowski. 1996. “The Impact of the International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview.” In Internationalization and Domestic Politics, pp. 25-47. Edited by Robert Keohane and Helen Milner. Cambridge University Press.

Haggard, Stephan and Chung H. Lee. 1995. Financial Systems and Economic Policy in Developing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Haggard, Stephan and Sylvia Maxfield. 1996. “The Political Economy of Financial Internationalization in the Developing World.” In Internationalization and Domestic Politics, pp. 209-39.  Edited by Robert Keohane and Helen Milner. Cambridge University Press.

Hutchcroft, Paul.1998. Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press.

Goodman, John and Louis Pauly. 1993. “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls? Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets.” World Politics 46(1): 50-82.

Kurzer, Paulette. 1991. “Unemployment in Open Economies: The Impact of Trade, Finance and European Integration.” Comparative Political Studies 24(April): 3-30.

_______________. 1993. Business and Banking: Political Change and Economic Integration in Western Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Lee, Chung H. and Stephan Haggard. 1995. “Introduction: Issues and Findings.” In Financial Systems and Economic Policy in Developing Countries, pp. 1-27. Edited by S. Haggard and C. H. Lee. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Mendoza, Amado Jr. 1995. “Who’s Wagging the Dog?: State, Rent-Seeking and Finance in South Korean NIC-hood.” Kasarinlan 11(1-2):149-174.

______________. 1996. “Democracy and Economic Growth: What’s in Store for South Korea?” Kasarinlan 12 (1): 45-70.

Montes, Manuel and Johnny Noe E. Ravalo. 1995. “The Philippines.” In Financial Systems and Economic Policy in Developing Countries, pp. 140-81. Edited by S. Haggard and C. H. Lee. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Nam, Sang-woo and C. H. Lee. 1995. “Korea.” In Financial Systems and Economic Policy in Developing Countries, pp. 31-55. Edited by S. Haggard and C. H. Lee. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Pauly, Louis. 1988. Opening Financial Markets: Banking Politics on the Pacific Rim. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Rosenbluth, Frances. 1989. Financial Politics in Contemporary Japan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

Suleik, Mercedes. 1992. “Banking and Financial Reforms in the Philippines (Part 2).” CB Review 44(1):13-17.

Winters, Jeffrey. 1994. “Power and the Control of Capital.” World Politics 46(4): 419-52.

World Bank. 1988. Philippines: Financial Sector Study. Industry and Energy Operations Division, Country Department II.


House vs. Senate

Major issues in the legislative debate included how many foreign banks would be allowed to enter, their mode of entry, how much capitalization would be required of the new entrants, and how many branches each would be entitled to open up.  The bill enacted by the Senate in April 1994 (SB 1606) was far more restrictive than that earlier passed by the House (HB 8226).  It permitted only six to eight new entrants (rather than leaving the matter up to the Monetary Board, as did the House bill), required $16 million in capitalization (rather than the roughly $5 million required by the House), and sanctioned only six branches for each of the foreign banks, whether existing or new entrant (rather than giving the foreign banks the same privileges as the domestic banks).  As to the mode of entry, SB 1606 hewed closely to the Angara-Roco-Ople version.  First, it disallowed the entry of foreign banks as a wholly-owned and controlled subsidiary incorporated under Philippine laws, which the House version permitted. Second, while HB 8226 allowed foreign banks to own up to 70% of the voting stock of an existing Philippine bank, the Senate version limits foreign ownership to 60% of a bank, whether existing or newly established.  Third, the Senate version restricts the entry of foreign banks to only one mode of entry.  The appropriate section of SB 1606 read:

Sec. 2.  Modes of Entry. – The Monetary Board may authorize foreign banks to operate in the Philippine banking system through any of the following modes: (I) by acquiring, purchasing or owning up to SIXTY PERCENT (60%) of the voting stock of an existing bank; (ii) by investing in up to SIXTY PERCENT (60%) of the voting stock of a new banking subsidiary incorporated under the laws of the Philippines; or (iii) by establishing branches with full banking authority: Provided, That a foreign bank may avail itself of only one (1) mode of entry: Provided, further, That a foreign bank or a Philippine corporation may own up to sixty percent (60%) of the voting stock of only one (1) domestic bank or new banking subsidiary.

How the banks positioned themselves in the debate

The major argument of the BAP was that, to ensure a ‘level playing field,’ foreign and domestic banks should have the same minimum capitalization requirements ($27 million for non-unibanks).  On the question of branches, however, they desired a most uneven field: retention of the three-branch limit for foreign banks, thus ensuring that the vast bulk of depositors would remain outside the reach of external competition.  As the debate heated up, the BAP waged a media campaign to weaken the extent of actual liberalization and support the more restrictive Senate bill.

The four foreign banks already in the system—in particular Citibank, by far the largest and most influential of the four—actively supported the less restrictive terms of entry.  It is believed that while these banks would be most directly affected by the entry of new foreign banks, a strong desire for more branches was apparently a stronger consideration.

As the bicameral conference committee convened to reconcile the differences between the two bills, tensions escalated between House and Senate, foreign and domestic banks, avid and reluctant reformers.  After deadlocks among key sponsors, the House and the Senate forged a May 1994 compromise allowing the entry of ten foreign banks and sticking with the Senate’s earlier six-branch restriction on the scope of their operations.  Minimum capitalization of roughly $9 million allowed three branches, and $13.5 million the rights to six.  The new law also provided a second mode of entry for foreign banks: up to 60 percent ownership of a domestically incorporated bank (as compared to the 30% to 40% permissible since the 1970s).  The BAP made no effort to hide its pleasure over the compromise; BAP president Rafael Buenaventura[1] explained that the final law “met [our] standard in terms of balancing the national interest with the country’s need for globalization without making too many unnecessary concessions.”[2]

Twenty-one banks applied for entry and in early 1995 the ‘magic’ ten were selected.  These include Australia and New Zealand (ANZ) Bank, Bangkok Bank, Chemical Bank, Development Bank of Singapore, Deutsche Bank, Fuji Bank, International Commercial Bank of China, Internationale Nederlanden Groep (ING) Bank[3], Korea Exchange Bank, and Bank of Tokyo.  Three of these banks—Chemical, Deutsche, and Tokyo—were not exactly new since they had offshore banking units (OBUs) in the country prior to 1995.  By 1996, all had opened shop—and by the way they did so it was evident that their direct impact on competition would likely be confined to the very top end of the market, which was already competitive.  In general, they established offices on the upper floors of Makati skyscrapers and did not bother with the expense of lobbies or tellers.[4]  In effect, the new banks will compete in the corporate banking and trade financing, segment of the market where there’s already keen competition.  Even Citibank, the only foreign bank that may begin to have the institutional strength to tap a larger segment of the market, shied away from the market’s lower end.  It has yet to complete the six-branch quota since it only has four branches so far—Makati, Greenhills, Libis Citi-Square (the newest branch inaugurated by no less than President Estrada last April 2000), and Cebu.

To be concluded….

___________________________________________________________

[1] Mr. Buenaventura is the current governor of the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP).

[2] Rafael Buenaventura, “At the Forefront of Change,” Fookien Times Philippines Yearbook 1994, p. 180.

[3]When the British merchant bank, Baring Brothers, collapsed due to the uncontrolled trading of a rogue trader, it was acquired by ING.  In the process, ING Philippines also acquired Baring Securities (Philippines).

[4] Of the ten, only the Development Bank of Singapore (DBS) opened more than one branch, presumably to better oversee remittance of foreign exchange by Filipino OCWs in Singapore to relatives in the Philippines.


The legislative battle lines are drawn

In the first regular session of Congress (2nd semester of 1992), Representatives Edmigdio Tanjuatco, Jr., Margarito Teves, and Alberto Veloso authored House Bill 263 entitled “An Act Liberalizing the Entry and Scope of Operations of Foreign Banks in the Philippines, Amending for the purpose RA 337, otherwise known as the General Banking Act.” They were joined by “additional authors as manifested on the floor”: Miguel Romero, Jose Ramirez, Ramon Bagatsing, Jr., Renato Dragon, Rodolfo Albano, Dante Liban, and Angelito Sarmiento.

All of the above named representatives, save for Dragon, were not connected with the banking industry.  Dragon headed a savings bank based in Cavite before he was elected to the House.  Then in March 1993, HB 223 was substituted by HB 8226 carrying the same title.  HB 8226 had Teves as its principal author: Teves was joined this time by 65 other members of the House as co-authors.  Of this 65 co-authors, only Manuel Villar, Jr., and Ricardo Silverio  were associated with the banking industry.  But Villar only headed the Capitol Bank, another thrift bank, and is not associated with any commercial bank.  Silverio was once associated with Pilipinas Bank but only during the Marcos years.

After two months, on May 17, 1993, HB 8226 was approved on second reading by the House.  A month later, it was approved on third and final reading with an overwhelming 120-2 vote with no abstentions.  The Senators were less united than their counterparts in the House of Representatives.  Three versions were introduced in 1992: Senate Bill 839 by Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo, SB 1474 by Senators Edgardo Angara, Raul Roco and Blas Ople, and SB 1563 by Senator Leticia Ramos-Shahani.  These SBs were soon consolidated into SB 1606 in April 1994.[1]

An examination of the three SBs indicate that Shahani’s version is the most liberal one while the Angara-Roco-Ople version is the most restrictive one.  For instance, on the matter of the entry of foreign banks, the Shahani version had a section that explicitly allowed the entry of foreign banks.  The Arroyo version took the tack of repealing section 11 of the General Banking Act (GBA) that explicitly prohibited the entry of new foreign banks into the country. Meanwhile, the Angara-Roco-Ople version did not contain any provision that either explicitly allowed the entry of new banks or repealed GBA’s section 11.  Arroyo’s version was closest to HB 8226 while Shahani’s bill was apparently more liberal than the already liberal House version.

On the question, for instance, of the mode of entry of new foreign banks, the House and Arroyo versions both provided for three possible modalities: establishment of branches for the four existing foreign banks; establishment of wholly- or majority-owned and controlled banking subsidiaries; and to invest in new shares of stocks or acquire into existing foreign-owned stocks up to 70% of the voting stock of an existing bank.  Under the first modality, Bank of America, Citibank, Hongkong and Shanghai Bank,  and Standard Chartered Bank can open new branches.  Under the second mode, a new foreign bank, for example Dresdner Bank of Germany may decide to establish Dresdner Bank (Philippines) and could own up to 100% of its voting stock.  In the third option, a foreign bank that already has a stake in an existing Philippine bank may opt to increase its share in the same bank.  For example, Chemical Bank of New York, which already had a stake in Far East Bank, may increase its investment in the same bank.  Or it could also happen that Citibank may want to buy into Far East Bank by buying Chemical Bank’s share.  The Shahani version goes beyond the three options mentioned in HB 8226 and proceeds to specify what kinds of business the foreign banks can undertake in the country.  They include:

  • “Lending of funds obtained from the public through receipt of deposits provided that all peso deposits shall not be vested in any manner outside the Philippines”;
  • General banking business; and
  • “Maintain by themselves or by assignee any suit for the recovery of any debt, claim, or demand whatsoever” (Comparative Analysis 1993).

On the other hand, the Angara-Roco-Ople version does not contain any provision on the mode of entry of new foreign banks (as it was equally silent on the entry of new banks), capital requirements, expansion of foreign banks’ scope of operations within the Philippines, and the general guidelines for the approval of entry of the new foreign banks.  It was as if the three senators were not in favor of the entry of new foreign banks at all.  The only concession that the three senators allowed in this direction was to increase the foreign equity ownership in existing Philippine banks from 30% allowed by the GBA to 50% of voting stock.  The other Senate versions and HB 8226 were more liberal allowing from a maximum of 70-100% in foreign ownership of banks organized according to Philippine law.  In effect, the three simply wanted to keep the existing number of commercial banks in place.  In so far as this version is concerned, they were not even in favor of allowing Bank of America et al to increase the number of their branches in the country.

In delineating the guidelines for the approval of entry of new foreign banks, the Shahani version was more liberal compared to HB 8226.  It adopted all of the HB 8226’s stipulations except the ‘reciprocity’ requirement.  The House version required that only applications from banks domiciled in countries that also allow the operation of Philippine banks in their jurisdictions will be qualified.  The Shahani version dropped this restriction altogether (Comparative Analysis 1993).

The political alignments in both legislative chambers must be reviewed in order to put in proper context the dynamics underlying the process of passing the Bank Liberalization Law of 1994 (R.A. 7721, entitled “An Act Liberalizing the Entry and Scope of Operations of Foreign Banks in the Philippines and for other Purposes).  President Ramos run and won under the banner of Lakas-NUCD, a breakaway party from the Laban ng Demokratikong Pilipino (LDP).  In the House of Representatives, Ramos’ able lieutenant, House speaker Jose de Venecia not only to managed to raid the LDP ranks and entice many into the Lakas fold but also forged a ‘Rainbow Coalition’ composed of incumbents from Lakas, LDP, the Liberal Party, the Nationalist Peoples’ Coalition (NPC), and the Nacionalista Party that invariably supported administration bills. And the Bank Liberalization Law was definitely an administration bill.

In the Senate, however, Lakas had only two senators, Shahani and Santanina Rasul.  Furthermore, the Lakas senators were relative lightweights especially in economic issues compared to the LDP stalwarts who dominated the Senate in terms of influence and prestige—Angara, Roco, Ople, Arroyo, Alberto Romulo, and Neptali Gonzales. Only in late 1994 did the Lakas and the LDP enter into a coalition with each other, a union rhapsodized by columnist Amando Doronilla as the dawning of a new, issue-based politics in the country while derided by other media pundits as the marriage of convenience of not-so-innocent harlots.

The 1992 Senate versions however indicate some fissures within LDP with Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo hewing closely to Ramos’ overall program of economic liberalization.  Angara, Roco and Ople appear to be still wedded to the protectionist, rent-seeking past, for good reason.  Before becoming legislators, Angara and Roco were stalwarts of the top-drawer ACCRA law firm, which counted among its many clients the top corporations, financial or otherwise, of the country.  Between the two, Roco was clearly associated with a family group, the Sorianos who had strong interests in San Miguel Corporation and controlled a middling commercial bank, the Asian Bank.  Angara, meanwhile developed strong links with the coconut monopoly established during the Marcos years and headed by Eduardo “Danding” Cojuangco, who in turn had substantial holdings in the United Coconut Planters Bank and San Miguel Corporation.

To be continued…..

_______________________________________________

[1]  A document entitled “Comparative Analysis Between RA 337, HB 8226, SB 839, SB 1474, SB 1563” and dated 10 January 1993 is the basic source of information for the subsequent discussion.  Unfortunately, the document does not indicate any author, and the author forgot the exact provenance of the same.  For purposes of citation in text, it will be subsequently referred to as Comparative Analysis 1993.


Bank liberalization under Ramos, serious this time around

The Ramos administration, in addition to creating a new monetary authority, also pushed for a substantial program of banking liberalization.  Concretely, this meant allowing the entry of new banks (domestic and foreign) and easing branching privileges for these same banks.  Pressures for opening up the industry can be traced to the 1988 World Bank report, which argued that “the strong domestic banks should not feel forever insulated from competition.”[1]  But initial response was essentially limited to the Central Bank’s March 1989 declaration that purported to remove restrictions on new commercial bank licenses[2] and reorient other key aspects of supervisory policy.

This display of reformist zeal, however, was probably meant to have more impact on the release of the first tranche of the World Bank’s financial sector adjustment loan than on the financial sector itself.  No new banking licenses were granted until Central Bank governor Jose Cuisia’s term began in 1990—and then only up to two savings banks (Family Savings Bank and Philippine Savings Bank), which were allowed to upgrade themselves to commercial banks.  In fact, no genuinely new players were allowed into the system until 1994.  Under Cuisia, the only real progress toward liberalization was the loosening of previously tight restrictions on the opening of new branches.[3]  The broader reform initiative of the late years of President Corazon Aquino’s regime was the ‘New Economic Program’ launched by finance secretary Jesus Estanislao in 1990.  While it included a by-now pro-forma denunciation of the cartel-type practices of banks, no serious challenge to the banking sector was attempted.  In fact, even the central element of the Estanislao program—tariff reform—was thwarted by import-substitution-industrialization (ISI) interests (Hutchcroft 1998).

By 1992, a combination of international and domestic factors promoted much greater momentum toward a wide-reaching program of economic liberalization.  The administration of President Fidel V. Ramos displayed new understanding of the country’s place in the world economy, and a clear sense of its weakness in competing effectively in the international and regional arenas.  This new momentum was manifested by a significant degree of liberalization of foreign exchange, foreign investment, and trade; as well as a major challenge to the cartels and monopolies in telecommunications and inter-island shipping.  In time, Ramos’ advisers and other advocates of liberalization trained their sights on the banking sector.

Even before Ramos assumed the presidency in mid-1992, the Central Bank was seriously mulling over plans to liberalize the banking sector by allowing the entry of new players.  A senior CB official, Mercedes Suleik (1992, p. 15) wrote in the CB Review: “the Central Bank is reviewing the restrictive policy on the entry of foreign banks in the Philippines with a view to recommending to Congress liberalization of these statuary restrictions in line with the overall policy of encouraging foreign investments.”  By law, foreign banks are not authorized to operate in the Philippines with the exception of foreign bank branches already operating when the General Banking Act took effect in 1949.  The same law also provided that at least 70% of the voting equity of banks organized under Philippine law must be owned by Filipino citizens.  Furthermore, the four foreign banks were prohibited from opening new branches within the Philippines, barred from accepting deposits from government, and could rarely avail of the CB rediscount facility.

In an address before the European Chamber of Commerce of the Philippines (ECCP) in March 1992, CB Governor Cuisia informed the European businessmen that “the Central Bank supports moves to liberalize the entry of foreign banks which, with their large capital base and established track record, can contribute to a stronger and more efficient banking system” (CB Review April 1992, p. 2).

Liberalization efforts were assisted by earlier disruption in the cordial relations that had long existed within the banking industry.  In particular, the introduction of automated teller machines (ATMs)[4] in the late 1980s encouraged growing tensions between the stronger domestic banks and the foreign banks.[5]  While the domestic banks were rapidly expanding their share of the lower end of the deposit market (where funds could be obtained at generally negative real interest rates[6]), the foreign banks were restricted to three branches and forced to raise funds at the upper end of the deposit market (at much higher, positive real rates of interest).  In response to these limitations, Citibank publicized in 1991 a careful analysis of the large intermediation spreads earned by Philippine-based banks.  While high reserve requirements and other regulatory factors partially accounted for the big spread, Citibank economists asserted that “oligopolistic market power” was also very much to blame.  They further declared that banks with greatest access to regular deposits (the largest domestic banks) were enjoying “excessive profit margins,” and should begin paying savers positive real rates of return (with “risk premium for keeping their savings in the Philippines”).  Their analysis concluded by urging that the overall system be “gradually deregulated” and opened to new entrants.  In a letter of response, the president of the Bankers Association of the Philippines (BAP)[7] made clear that Citibank’s public break with the ranks was not appreciated[8] ( Hutchcroft 1998, pp. 213-4).

As momentum for liberalization gathered steam over the next two years, the BAP eventually adopted the approach of supporting reform in general terms but curbing it as much as possible in its specifics.  This became most apparent in 1993, when the Ramos administration proposed its major initiative for the banking sector: allowing more foreign banks to establish wholly-owned operations in the country.  The number of banks enjoying such privileges was restricted to four—Citibank, Bank of America, Chartered Bank, and Hong-Kong & Shanghai Bank—in the late 1940s.

As debate over the entry of more foreign banks shaped up in late 1993 and early 1994, the key question was not whether the reform would take place but how.  On one side of the debate were those favoring more liberal terms of entry: Ramos and his key advisers (particularly national security adviser Jose Almonte), the House of Representatives (in general very supportive of Ramos’ economic liberalization program), the four foreign banks, multilateral institutions, and the US government.  The side seeking to restrict the terms of entry was led by the BAP, which relied in turn on vital assistance from key allies in the Senate.

To be continued….

___________________________________________

[1] World Bank, Philippine Financial System (1988), vi.

[2] On May 16, 1989, the Central Bank issued CB Circular 1200 which lifted the moratorium on the establishment of new banks.

[3] Central Bank Circular 1281, dated April 15, 1991, provided many more branch licenses through an auction process.  Rural banks were also given the privilege of nationwide branching under Circular 1280 dated the same day.  An even more permissive policy was instituted in 1993, when branch licenses became available to any bank satisfying certain minimum capital requirements.

[4] The operation of ATMs was allowed, subject to certain regulations specified in CB Circular 1286, dated May 23, 1991.

[5] Up until the passage of the Bank Liberalization Law of 1994, only four foreign banks were given CB licenses to undertake full commercial banking operations in the Philippines.  They were Bank of America, Citibank, Hong Kong & Shanghai Bank, and the Standard Chartered Bank.  In 1977, other foreign banks were allowed to establish presence and operate in the Philippines but only as offshore banking units (OBUs).  As OBUs, these banks can only conduct offshore banking business—acceptance of deposits from non-Philippine residents and lending to non-residents and to Philippine banks and the Central Bank of the Philippines, as well as other government agencies as authorized by the CB. Later on, these OBUs were allowed to negotiate incoming export letters of credit (LCs) and to provide full foreign exchange services for all foreign currency non-trade remittances (Suleik 1992).

[6] When the interest rates that banks pay to their depositors are lower than the prevailing inflation rates, real interest rates are negative or are below zero.  When real interest rates are negative, the bank depositor would be better off spending or using his cash elsewhere rather than depositing the same in the bank.

[7] All the commercial banks, domestic and foreign, including Citibank were members of the Bankers Association of the Philippines (BAP).

[8] Citibank study, “Bank Intermediation Spreads,” unpublished manuscript, n.d. [1991?]; Letter from Xavier P. Loinaz, president of the BAP (and the Bank of the Philippine Islands), to William Ferguson, Citibank vice president, Febuary 1, 1991.